Author's personal copy An evaluation of the targets and timetables of proposed Australian emissions reduction policies

نویسنده

  • Roger A. Pielke
چکیده

This paper evaluates Australia’s proposed emissions reduction policies in terms of the implied rates of decarbonization of the Australian economy for a range of proposed emissions reduction targets. The paper uses the Kaya Identity to structure the evaluation, employing both a bottom-up approach (based on projections of future Australian population, economic growth, and technology) as well as a top-down approach (deriving implied rates of decarbonization consistent with the targets and various rates of economic growth). Both approaches indicate that the Australian economy would have to achieve annual rates of decarbonization of 3.8–5.9% to meet a 2020 target of reducing emissions by 5%, 15% or 25% below 2000 levels, and about 5% to meet a 2050 target of a 60% reduction below 2000 levels. The paper argues that proposed Australian carbon policy proposals present emissions reduction targets that will be all but impossible to meet without creative approaches to accounting as they would require a level of effort equivalent to the deployment of dozens of new nuclear power plants or thousands of new solar thermal plants within the next decade. # 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. E-mail addresses: [email protected], [email protected]. avai lable at www.sc iencedi rec t .com journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/envsci 1462-9011/$ – see front matter # 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2010.10.008 Author's personal copy Upon the release of an interim draft of the Garnaut Review in February, 2008, commissioned by the Australian government to inform its climate policy deliberations, Professor Garnaut called for Australia to increase its targets beyond those mentioned at Bali: ‘‘Australia should be ready to go beyond its stated 60% reduction target by 2050 in an effective global agreement that includes developing nations (Daley, 2008). Immediately thereafter, Prime Minster Rudd’s government appeared to distance itself from the report. Climate Change Minister Penny Wong said of the report’s conclusions, ‘‘We welcome Professor Garnaut’s input. . . . of course we will also be looking at other inputs, such as modelling from the Australian Treasury’’, prompting the leader of the Australian Green party to complain that, ‘‘Penny Wong has reduced Ross Garnaut to ‘input’’’ (Porteous and Williams, 2008). Garnaut’s draft report was issued on July 4, 2008 and the final report was released on September 30, 2008. Less than two weeks after the draft Garnaut review was released the Rudd government released a ‘‘Green Paper’’ outlining its initial plans for a Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme (CPRS), a policy based on a cap-and-trade approach to emissions reductions along the lines of the European Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). A ‘‘White Paper’’ outlining the final plans for the proposed CPRS was subsequently released in December, 2008, as the Australian government announced a emissions reductions target of between 5% (unilaterally) and 15% (in concert with other nations) reduction below 2020 levels, and a proposed 60% reduction by 2050 (Commonwealth of Australia, 2008). In the face of severe criticism for its lack of ambition (Foley, 2008) the government justified its target in terms of the implications for per capita emissions, which it argued were on par with those promised by other nations. It was not long before the Rudd government responded to its critics who said that the targets were not ambitions enough. In May, 2009 the interim target was increased to a 25% reduction and the proposed starting implementation date for the CPRS was delayed to 2011, justified on the need to allow the economy to regain strength in the aftermath of the global financial crisis (Australian Government, 2009a). In August 2009, the Australian Senate voted down the CPRS, prompting the government to split the renewable energy provisions from the ETS. The renewable energy package was subsequently passed into law. In November, 2009 the opposition Liberal Party saw a revolt over the proposed CPRS, resulting in a change in party leadership and a subsequent second defeat for the ETS in the Senate. In April, 2010 the Australian government shelved the emissions trading legislation until 2013, leaving its future status highly uncertain (Kirk, 2010). One consequence of this decision was a dramatic loss in public support for Prime Minister Rudd, contributing to his ouster by the Labor Party and replacement by Julia Gillard. Gillard, who was among those who recommended postponing the emissions trading legislation, inherited the expectations and promises for action on climate change. Gillard was narrowly retained as prime minister following a historic election in August, 2010, based on the slimmest of parliamentary majorities. Gillard subsequently appointed a new committee to consider options for Australia’s climate policy. While debate over policies such as emissions trading and a potential carbon tax is sure to continue in Australia for an extended period despite its legislative uncertainty, it is possible to conduct an assessment of the targets implied by proposed versions of the ETS. This paper provides an evaluation of Australia’s proposed emissions reductions targets. How realistic are Australia’s proposed emissions reductions goals on the short and long term? This paper focuses on emissions reductions targets of 5%, 15% and 25% from 2000 levels by 2020 (Australian Government, 2009b). The paper argues that Australia’s emissions reductions policy proposals are based on targets that will be all but impossible to meet without creative approaches to accounting. Australia provides yet another case study in the enormous difference between the rhetoric and the practice of emissions reductions. 2. Methodology of evaluation The methodology employed here was employed in Pielke (2009a,b) to structure similar analyses of the United Kingdom’s Climate Change Act and the Japanese ‘‘Mamizu’’ climate policy. It draws upon Waggoner and Ausubel (2002) who argue that understanding the ability to influence environmental outcomes through policy requires ‘‘quantifying the component forces of environmental impact and integrating them’’. For carbon dioxide emissions relationship of forces leading to carbon dioxide emissions has been called the Kaya Identity, and it can be used to decompose the factors that lead to carbon dioxide emissions from the production and use of energy in the global economy. The identity is comprised of two primary factors: economic growth (or contraction), typically represented in terms of GDP, and changes in technology, typically represented as carbon dioxide emissions per unit GDP. Each of these two primary factors is typically broken down into a further two sub-factors. GDP growth (or contraction) is comprised of changes in population and in per capita GDP. Carbon dioxide emissions per unit GDP is represented by the product of energy intensity, which refers to energy per unit of GDP and carbon intensity, which refers to the amount of carbon per unit of energy. Together the four factors of the Kaya Identity explain the various influences that contribute to increasing atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide, as follows: (1) Carbon dioxide emissions = population per capita GDP energy intensity carbon intensity (2) P = total population (3) GDP/P = per capita GDP a. GDP = economic growth (contraction) = P GDP/P = GDP (4) Energy intensity (EI) = TE/GDP = total energy (TE) consumption/GDP b. Carbon intensity (CI) = C/TE = carbon emissions/total energy consumption 1 The methodological description is reproduced here as this paper is intended as a stand-alone analysis. Readers familiar with Pielke (2009a,b) can skip to the next section. e n v i r o n m e n t a l s c i e n c e & p o l i c y 1 4 ( 2 0 1 1 ) 2 0 – 2 7 21 Author's personal copy (5) EI CI = ‘‘carbon intensity of the economy’’ = TE/GDP C/ TE = C/GDP. Thus, according to the logic of these relationships, carbon accumulating in the atmosphere can be reduced only by reducing (a) population, (b) per capita GDP, or (c) carbon intensity of the economy. Most proposals advanced by governments and in international negotiations focus on actions that will lead to the reduction of the carbon intensity of the economy (whether or not they are explicitly presented as such), which in this paper is referred to as ‘‘decarbonization’’. Policies to reduce population or that result in economic contraction are not generally considered by governments as a strategy of emissions reductions. Thus, the Kaya Identity provides a straightforward and useful way to evaluate the proposed and actual performance of policies focused on decarbonization and which are typically called mitigation policies. The factors of the Kaya Identity can be used to evaluate these estimates in terms of what is required to achieve the identified goals. The factors can be integrated individually, in ‘‘bottom up’’ fashion based on independent projections for growth in population (2) and per capita GDP (3), to estimate implied rates of decarbonization (5). The overall goal can also be disaggregated in a ‘‘top down’’ manner, starting with overall GDP growth (a) and deriving implied rates of decarbonization (5) consistent with a specified target. The following sections consider each approach from a base year of 2006, which in most cases is the latest year for which data necessary for the analysis is available. 3. Evaluating Australian climate policy: part 1, a bottom up analysis The first factor in the Kaya Identity is overall population, since more people means more emissions, all else equal. In 2008, the UN published its World Population Prospects and projected an Australian growth rate of 1.0% per year to 2020 and 0.7% to 2050 (United Nations, 2009). If these rates were to occur to 2020 and 2050, then Australia would have about 23.7 million people in 2020 and 28.7 million in 2050, representing an increase of almost 2.2 and 7.2 million people respectively from 2010. The Australian government has much more aggressive population projections than those of the UN: ‘‘Australia’s estimated resident population (ERP) at 30 June 2007 of 21.0 million people is projected to increase to between 30.9 and 42.5 million people by 2056’’ (Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2008). A population of 40 million in 2050 would be about 20.5 million more than in 2010, and represent an annual growth rate of about 1.6% per year. The very large differences in projections underscore uncertainties in population projections. In 2005 Australian carbon dioxide emissions were about 19.4 t per person. If a 2050 population of 28.7 million had per capita emissions of 19.4 t, then total Australian emissions would be about 557 Mt of carbon dioxide, about 55% higher than 2000 levels of about 360 Mt. A 2020 population of 23.7 million at 19.4 t of carbon dioxide per person would result in about 459 Mt of carbon dioxide, about 28% below 2000 levels. A population of 40 million in 2050 would have 776 Mt of carbon dioxide emissions at 19.4 t per person, or 216% higher than 2000 levels. So an increasing population would mean that Australia’s emissions will increase, all else equal. Population growth compounds the difficulty of meeting national targets for emissions reductions. The second factor in the Kaya identity is economic activity. All else being equal more economic activity means more emissions. From 1990 to 2006 Australia averaged 3.4% per year annual GDP growth (in constant currency, i.e., inflation adjusted). If overall growth to 2050 is expected to occur at its historical average of 3.5% per year, and population is growing by 0.7–1.6% per year, then this implies a per capita GDP growth rate of 1.9–2.8% per year. Of course, governments strive for higher growth rates and a vibrant economy, just as they are now doing around the world to stimulate economic growth. For purposes of the present discussion, let us assume that future per capita GDP growth in Australia increases at 3.0% per year, reflecting a value in between the UN and Australian government population projections, and below its historical performance. This level of growth would add another 1000 Mt of carbon dioxide to the 2050 total, for a total of about 1361 Mt, about 3.8 times higher than 2000 emissions and about 6.3 times a 2050 target of a 60% reduction from 2005 levels. In 2020 this rate of growth would add about another 201 Mt of carbon dioxide emissions, for a total of 561 Mt, or 56% above 2000 emissions. The third factor is technological change. As described above, technological change includes increased energy efficiency in the economy and in reduced carbon intensity of energy. According to data from the United States Energy Information Agency from 2001 to 2006 on Australian total primary energy production, Australian energy intensity decreased by about 1.4% per year, while the carbon intensity of the energy supply increased by about 0.6% per year over the same period. However, the Australian economy did not decarbonize from 1995 to 2006, and, in fact recarbonzied from 2003 to 2006, so annual rates of decarbonization can be a bit misleading. Overall, the decarbonization of the Australian economy has occurred at an average rate of less than 1% per year based on US EIA data from 2001 to 2006. Using a bottom up analysis, the combined effects of Australian population and per capita economic growth of 3.0% per year imply that to meet a 2020 emissions reduction target of 5%, 15% or 25% below 2000 levels would require that the combined effects of increasing energy efficiency and reduced carbon intensity of energy occur at an average annual rate of 4.3%, 5.0% and 5.9% respectively to 2020 and 5.2% to 2050 for a 60% reduction target. 2 The terminology of ‘‘bottom up’’ and ‘‘top down’’ is simply descriptive of the approach used in this paper. 3 GDP data from Maddison (2008). 4 International Energy Statistics available at http://www.eia. doe.gov/emeu/international/contents.html, energy efficiency is the inverse of energy intensity, so an increase in efficiency is the same as a decrease in intensity, and vice versa. 5 Calculated using energy and carbon dioxide data from the US Energy Information Administration. e n v i r o n m e n t a l s c i e n c e & p o l i c y 1 4 ( 2 0 1 1 ) 2 0 – 2 7 22 Author's personal copy 4. Evaluating Australian climate policy: part 2, a top down analysis A top down analysis begins with assumptions of future economic growth, which integrates future population growth and per capita economic growth, and then works backwards to determine what rate of decarbonization of the economy would be necessary to meet the future emissions target. In 2006 Australia produced 0.84 t of carbon dioxide for every $1000 of GDP. Fig. 1 shows required rates of decarbonization of the Australian economy from 2007 to 2050 (for various rates of assumed GDP growth) implied by a target of a 60% reduction in carbon dioxide emissions from 2000 levels. The top down analysis uses a range of assumptions for future economic growth. In this analysis, five rates were used from 1 to 3% per year, which spans a wide range of possibilities. Fig. 1 shows that in one sense the choice of rates is not particularly important because the carbon intensity of the economy would have to decline to below 0.20 under all assumptions. The figure shows that the carbon intensity of the Australian economy would have to reach a level of 0.08–0.19 t of carbon dioxide per $1000 of GDP by 2050, from 0.84 in 2006. Fig. 2a–c shows the same information for 2020 implied by targets of 25%, 15% and 5% reduction in carbon dioxide levels from 2000 levels. The figure shows that the carbon intensity of the Australian economy would have to be cut by about a quarter to more than half by 2020, depending upon assumptions, from its value of 0.84 in 2006. Fig. 3 below shows the actual annual rate of decarbonization of the Australian economy from 1980 to 2006 as well as the annual average rates of decarbonization implied by the 2020 and 2050 targets assuming an average 2.5% annual GDP growth. A 2.5% growth rate is simply chosen as illustrative, but may be more realistic in the near term than the higher rate suggested by the bottom up analysis due to the global economic slowdown in recent years. Higher rates of future GDP growth would result in higher implied rates of decarbonization. The rates of decarbonization of the Australian economy implied by the top down analysis for a 25% reduction target from 2000 levels are 5.4% per year for the 2020 target and 4.8% for the 2050 target. These numbers are substantially higher than the rates of decarbonization observed from 1980 to 2006 and 2001 to 2006, as summarized in the table below, along with the rates derived for the bottom up analysis (Table 1). 5. Australian targets in context The Australian targets imply that Australia would have to achieve the 2006 emissions intensity of Japan by 2016 for a 25% reduction target, by 2018 for a 15% reduction target or 2020 for a 5% reduction target. Japan has a highly efficient economy on several small islands with almost no domestic energy resources. Japan also operates the third most nuclear power plants after the United States and France. In other words, in many important respects Japan could not be more different than Australia in terms of the role of emissions in its economy. [()TD$FIG] Fig. 1 – Implied rates of decarbonization of the Australian economy for a 60% reduction in emissions from 2000 levels by 2050 for various rates of GDP growth, 2007–2050. 6 Carbon dioxide data is available at: http://www.eia.doe.gov/ pub/international/iealf/tableh1co2.xls. Data on GDP, converted to 1990 Gheary-Khamis dollars (to facilitate international comparisons) is available at: http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/Historical_ Statistics/vertical-file_09-2008.xls. The 1990 Gheary-Khamis dollars are the units used throughout this paper. 7 These numbers reflect the assumptions of the bottom up approach. e n v i r o n m e n t a l s c i e n c e & p o l i c y 1 4 ( 2 0 1 1 ) 2 0 – 2 7 23 Author's personal copy

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

منابع مشابه

Decomposition and Analysis of Driving Forces of GHG Emissions and Emission Reduction Potentials in Iran

Climate change cannot control unless by reduction of GHG emissions to secure level, therefore it is important to identify driving forces and possible scenarios based on targets. In this research, the Logarithmic Mean Divisia Index decomposition approach in combination with Extended Kaya Identity (EKI) are applied to investigate five factors could affect emissions during 1971-2012 in Iran. Thes...

متن کامل

GHG Mitigation in Iran’s Energy Sector According to the National General Policies

The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change calls on member states to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions as much as possible in order to combat global warming. Iran has announced 4 and 12 percent emission reduction targets in 2030 in its Intended Nationally Determined Contributions compared to the Business-As-Usual (BAU) scenario, in which the energy sector has the largest shar...

متن کامل

GHG Mitigation in Iran’s Energy Sector According to the National General Policies

The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change calls on member states to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions as much as possible in order to combat global warming. Iran has announced 4 and 12 percent emission reduction targets in 2030 in its Intended Nationally Determined Contributions compared to the Business-As-Usual (BAU) scenario, in which the energy sector has the largest shar...

متن کامل

Reducing CO2 Emissions from Road Transport - Overview of the Main Initiatives and Technical Measures Proposed to Date in Europe

The demand for fossil fuel in the transport sector is constantly increasing and transportation is ranked amongst the highest greenhouse emitting sectors globally. Today, tackling CO2 emissions from road transport a widely discussed topic and constitutes a milestone towards reaching a sustainable, carbon neutral economy. This challenge is being described in various initiatives adopted in the ...

متن کامل

Analytical evaluation of an innovative decision-making algorithm for VM live migration

In order to achieve the virtual machines live migration, the two "pre-copy" and "post-copy" strategies are presented. Each of these strategies, depending on the operating conditions of the machine, may perform better than the other. In this article, a new algorithm is presented that automatically decides how the virtual machine live migration takes place. In this approach, the virtual machine m...

متن کامل

ذخیره در منابع من


  با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید

برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

عنوان ژورنال:

دوره   شماره 

صفحات  -

تاریخ انتشار 2010